Essay
No, it does not tell us much about political outcomes. Using the
presidential/semi-presidential/parliamentary
trichotomyThe threeway distinction
seems to originate from Alvarez, M., Cheibub, J. A., Limongi, F., & Przewroski, A. (1996). “Classifying political regimes.” Studies in Comparative International Development, 31(2), 3–36
to distinguish
between regimes does give us some information about likely outcomes, but
other, more nuanced, classifications of legislative-executive relations
provide far greater explanatory power. In particular, whilst there are
empirical differences in government formation, cabinet composition, and
democratic survival between presidential and parliamentary regimes, the
magnitude of within-type variation is so great that regime type alone
tells us only a little about political outcomes. Additional factors –
such as electoral system, number of veto players, and concentration of
political power – play a decisive role in determining political
outcomes. Importantly, there are only plausible accounts of why
institutional arrangements would cause political outcomes to differ as
they are observed to once such factors are brought into the picture. In
this essay, I will first outline the standard definitions of the three
regime types and introduce objections to this taxonomy, before exploring
empirical findings on what success the approach has in explaining the
variations in political outcomes that we observe.
One attraction of the presidential/semi-presidential/parliamentary
taxonomy is its simplicity. Presidential regimes are those in which in
which the government does not require the support of a legislative
majority to exist; if it does, the regime is either semi-presidential or
parliamentary – the former only if there is also a head of state
elected directly by voters for a fixed term (Cheibub
et al. 2010). Because the boundaries
between these categories
are binary and crispHmm, though
this paper suggests that there is debate around definitions of categories too. The conclusion
here seems to be that there were disagreements
over where to put countries, but now there is more conceptual clarity,
and so there are no longer (e.g. they’re able to say whether
classifications are “wrong” or not).
, modern criticisms of the taxonomy focus on
challenging the utility and coherence of its classifications, rather
than claiming that specific countries are incorrectly placed (Elgie
2020). Such objections are the most forceful – and have existed the
longest – in the case of the semi-presidential category, whose members
significantly differ from each other even in terms of de jure
constitutional arrangements. Many scholars argue that the group should
be subdivided into premier-presidential systems, where the government is
accountable only to the legislature, and president-parliamentary ones,
where the government is also accountable to the president (Elgie 2020).
Others, such as Lijphart (2012, 108) suggest that the semi-presidential
group can simply be
split up into and subsumed byDrawing on Clark et al. (2012, 504): Premier-presidential regimes are very similar to
parliamentary ones. President-parliamentary regimes are more distinctive, and their characteristics depend on the balance of power between at a particular time. However, the fact that a president-parliamentary country is either presidential-like or
parliamentary-like at a time and alternates between the two suggests that this designation does not add much on its own – we simply need to know what the electoral situation is and then treat it as one of the pure types in practice. On the other hand, you could argue that this capacity for oscillation is a unique and important feature of president-parliamentary systems, justifying making the distinction.
the other
two. Either way, given that there is
such limited consistencySome arguments against the coherence of semi-pres as a category
here. One response would be that empirically, countries with president-parliamentary systems are part-way between the two pure system types, as we would expect: “An implication … is that cabinets in president-parliamentary
democracies should be characterized by fewer partisan ministers and a
lower proportionality in the allocation of portfolios than in
parliamentary regimes but more partisan ministers and a higher
proportionality in the allocation of portfolios than in presidential
regimes. In fact, this is precisely what Amorim Neto and Strøm find in
their study of twelve parliamentary and twelve semi-presidential
democracies in Europe during the 1990s” (Clark et al. 2012, 511).
around legislative-executive relations in the semi-presidential group, it seems unjustified to suggest that merely
knowing that a country falls into that category could tell us much about
political outcomes there.
Therefore, let us focus on the two remaining categories of parliamentary
and presidential regimes, and investigate what distinguishing between
countries along these lines tells us about political outcomes. There are
three main areas where differences in average outcomes can be found:
government formation, cabinet composition, and democratic longevity. I
now examine each in turn, identifying the key empirical results, and,
crucially, analysing whether the presidential/parliamentary distinction
alone can convincingly explain the differences found.
Governments in presidential regimes are more likely to be in a
legislative minority and less likely to rule as a coalition than those
in parliamentary regimes. Looking at almost all democracies from
1946-99,
Cheibub et al. (2004, 575)This is cited in Clark et al. (2012, 501), which also references two other studies with different figures supporting the claim that presidential systems are more likely to lead to minority government: “It is widely recognized that about a third of all parliamentary governments are minority governments (Strøm 1990). In contrast, Amorim Neto (2006) finds that 46 percent (49) of the governments in presidential regimes in Latin America from the late 1970s to 2000 were minority governments.”
demonstrate that in
situations where no party had an absolute majority, a minority
government resulted 68% of the time in presidential regimes, but only
38% in parliamentary ones. The same study also showed that such
situations lead to coalition government around 30% less frequently in
presidential systems. The structure of legislative-executive relations
gives us a good reason to expect these differences: a parliamentary
government must as a minimum command implicit majority support in the
legislature to avoid a vote of no confidence, whereas this condition is
not required in presidential regimes. A similar logic explains why
coalitions are less likely: presidents have no need to offer ministerial
posts to opposing parties as a means of buying their support in the
legislature, because the government does not have to be backed by a
legislative majority. However, the extent to which this is true depends
on regime-specific factors such as how much the president is motivated
by purely office-seeking aims, and their ability to effect policies via
decree – the less true these both are, the more likely it is that
majority and coalition governments result in presidential regimes
(Clark et al. 2012, 511). So, knowing whether a regime
is parliamentary or presidential tells us a little about likely
government formation, with the caveat that the actual outcomes depend on
the
aims of the individual actors and the scope of legislative powersDoing a veto players analysis here might tell us more, though Colomer is against that (2006, 225) for reasons I don’t understand (his argument seems to be that the Tsebelis’s approach is too focussed on how institutions work in
practice so isn’t useful for constitutional design?). More saliently,
it doesn’t distinguish between autocratic one-party and democratic
one-party governments. Looking at concentration of power instead, as Colomer does, seems pretty closely related, but perhaps better.
held by the executive.
The ability of presidential governments to exist without majority
legislative support also contributes to differences in cabinet
composition compared to parliamentary ones. Presidential cabinets tend
to have more non-partisan ministers and a lower proportionality in the
allocation of ministerial posts (Samuels 2007, Table 29.1 & 29.2). As
above, this is because a minority president does not need to buy
legislative backing from other parties in the same way that a minority
prime minister would. However, there is an enormous amount of
within-group variation here, again explainable by the particular
president’s priorities and their capacity to directly legislate by
decree (Neto 2006). Therefore, whilst one can say that a randomly-chosen
presidential cabinet will typically have more non-partisanship and less
proportionality these features than a randomly-chosen parliamentary
one, the level of within-group variation means
that knowing a particular regime is presidential, on its own, tells you
very little about what to expectOn the basis of their Tobit
regressions (I couldn’t figure out what these are),
they say there is a statistically significant difference between presidential and
parliamentary systems. But that doesn’t mean that you get much information about a regime
from being told that it is one or the other!
of its cabinet composition.
Finally, presidential systems appear to be associated with
shorter-lived democraciesThere’s lots more discussion and statistics on this in Clark et al. (2012, 810-823), paraphrasing Mainwaring’s argument: “legislative fragmentation increases the likelihood of cabinet instability in parliamentary systems, whereas it increases the likelihood of democratic instability in presidential systems”. See also Samuels (2007, 706-7), who says that Przeworski et al. (2000) “reconfirm that presidentialism is more fragile than parliamentarism, but question the connection between party system attributes and presidential regime fragility.”
. Amongst democratic non-OECD countries
from 1973-89, the democratic survival rate for parliamentary regimes was
60%, triple that of presidential ones. Similar statistics exist for
robustness against coups and level of democracy, even when adjusting for
differences in economic and technological developmentThough it looks different if we also control for other explanatory variables. In Clark et al. (2012, 549): “Schleiter and Morgan-Jones (2009) find that if we take account
of government attributes and the constitutional rules surrounding the
dissolution of the legislature, then governments in
president-parliamentary democracies are no less stable than governments
in parliamentary democracies”
(Stepan & Skach
1993, 10). Causal conclusions must not be drawn too quickly,
though. As Colomer (2006, 230) notes, young democracies – those
most likely to have lapsed into undemocratic government – are almost
exclusively presidential in South America and pluralist parliamentary in
Eastern Europe. This tight association between region and regime type
strongly suggests that the kind of institutional arrangements decided on
in a new democracy is determined endogenously by factors such as
pre-existing political culture (Elgie 2020). If so, we should be wary of
attributing differences in political outcomes to regime type when both
are actually causally downstream from common variables not explicitly in
our model. Further cause for caution is provided by the fact that
parliamentary majoritarian regimes are
generally more unstable than the typical presidential regime, while
parliamentary pluralist regimes are the most peaceful of all (Colomer
2006, 230). Just like with government formation and cabinet composition,
the distinction between presidential, semi-presidential, and
parliamentary regimes is
insufficient to draw firm conclusionsSo, perhaps we should turn to the consensus/majoritarian distinction instead. On a scale from consensus to majoritarian, we’d have presidential, president-parliamentary (though it’s more consensus-based when there’s cohabitation, see Clark et al. (2012, 751)), premier-presidential, parliamentary. I think Lijphart argues
against doing this though. Also, as Colomer (2006, 223) argues, the consensus/majoritarian divide is not
super useful on its own, but could be a helpful “second
dimension” you add. Of course, the problem with doing this is that when breaking countries up into very tiny subgroups, you end up with extremely small samples to work with. And, muddying the waters further, “some
democracies that have primarily majoritarian institutions happen to be
presidential” (Clark et al. 2012, 765).
about
democratic stability. Indeed, as Cheibub et al. (2014) show, a country’s regime
classification is less useful than simply knowing when and where its
constitution was written in
predicting institutional featuresSee Table 2 in that paper for the details.
such as
whether the executive has powers to make decrees and vetoes. It would
thus be strange to suppose that the taxonomy can give us helpful
information about political outcomes in a country, given its inability
to predict even basic facts about executive-legislative relations which
are upstream of those terminal outcomes.
So, to conclude – no, distinguishing amongst regimes based on whether
they are presidential, semi-presidential or parliamentary does not tell
us much about political outcomes. Although differences in outcomes
between in the average presidential regime and the average parliamentary
regime are borne out by the data, the extent of within-type variation
means that this does not imply that we can draw useful inferences
about the political outcomes in a particular country on the basis of its
regime type. The substantial differences between premier-presidential
and president-parliamentary regimes mean that the semi-presidential
classification is particularly unhelpful. Precise predictions about
political outcomes can only be made once additional features, such as
position on the majoritarian/consensus axis, are incorporated into the
model. Therefore,
as I have arguedIt sounds like Przeworski (e.g. 2003) criticises the distinctions a lot. Could be worth looking at him.
, the
presidential/semi-presidential/parliamentary taxonomy is not informative about
political outcomes on its own, but can become valuable when used as part
of a multidimensional classification.
References
Cheibub, J.A., Gandhi, J. & Vreeland, J.R. (2010). Democracy and
dictatorship revisited. Public Choice 143, 67–101.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-009-9491-2
Cheibub, J.A., Elkins, Z. & Ginsburg, T. (2014). Beyond Presidentialism
and Parliamentarism. British Journal of Political Science, 44(3),
515-544. https://doi.org/10.1017/S000712341300032X
Clark, W.R., Golder, M. & Golder, S.N. (2012), “Chapter 12:
Parliamentary, Presidential, and Semi-Presidential Democracies: Making
and Breaking Governments”, in Principles of Comparative Politics (2nd
ed.). London: CQ Press.
Colomer, J.M. (2006). “Comparative Constitutions”, in The Oxford
Handbook of Political Institutions (ed. R. A. W. Rhodes, Sarah A.
Binder, and Bert A. Rockman). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Elgie, R. (2020). An Intellectual History of the Concepts of
Premier-Presidentialism and President-Parliamentarism. Political
Studies Review, 18(1), 12–29.
https://doi.org/10.1177/1478929919864770
Lijphart, A. (2012). “Chapter 7: Executive–Legislative Relations:
Patterns of Dominance and Balance of Power” in Patterns of Democracy:
Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries (2^nd^ ed.).
New Haven: Yale University Press.
Neto, O. A. (2006). The Presidential Calculus: Executive Policy Making
and Cabinet Formation in the Americas. Comparative Political Studies,
39(4), 415-440. https://doi.org./10.1177/0010414005282381
Rom, M.C., Hidaka, M. & Walker, R.B. (2022). “Semi-Presidential Regimes”
in Introduction to Political Science. Houston, TX: OpenStax.
Samuels, David (2007), “Separation of Powers”, in The Oxford Handbook
of Political Institutions (ed. R. A. W. Rhodes, Sarah A. Binder, and
Bert A. Rockman). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Stepan, A., & Skach, C. (1993). Constitutional Frameworks and Democratic
Consolidation: Parliamentarianism versus Presidentialism. World
Politics, 46(1), 1–22. https://doi.org/10.2307/2950664
- Excellent introduction. Very clear summary. Helpful conclusion too.
- Correct definition, although boundaries within the typology seem less
crisp than first assumed, given the issues on semi-pres. that you
discuss. The category is dismissed a bit too quickly, since it will also
influence conclusions for pres./parl.
- Good use of empirical evidence to answer the question. Good references
to the literature.
- Excellent point about causality. Perhaps you could have discussed
those other confounding factors more explicitly and in a bit more depth,
since this is the main critical point in your argument.
- Overall, very good essay. Well done!